This year we have featured the the proposal by Dr. Warren Coats to replace the US dollar with the SDR as the global reserve currency. This is because some (like Jim Rickards) have predicted that in the next big global financial crisis, the SDR will be put forward as a replacement for the US dollar in some way.
Dr. Coats has long had a real proposal to do this that could actually be considered by the IMF which to me makes it more significant than people who speculate on how this might work from outside the system. Dr. Coats has just circulated a draft of a new paper that summarizes his Currency Board proposal and provided me a copy to review and offer comments on. The draft is currently on a Word document so I pasted in the full article at the end of this blog article below so that you can read it in full. The paper also gives a historical background as to why he has made this proposal.
Dr. Coats has been very kind to answer various questions I have raised to him about his Currency Board proposal in the past. Recently, I asked him if he would be willing to answer some more direct questions I get from readers (and also see from people who comment on this on various forums on the internet).
The questions I asked this time were along the lines of why should the general public trust that central banks would follow the rules in his Currency Board proposal that would restrict their ability to create currency and also anchor it to a basket of goods (rather than leave it as a floating exchange rate against a basket of currencies as the SDR is now). Dr. Coats gave his answers to these questions and also permission to publish them here. Below are the questions and answers exactly as they appear in our email exchange on this.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Q: If we agree that over the past years the policies that have been used by central banks have sometimes resulted in poor results, misallocation of capital, asset bubbles, etc. despite the best efforts of good people (due to the limitations of human beings), why should we trust these same people to fix the current problems?
A: We should not leave it to the central bankers themselves to propose giving up floating exchange rates for hard anchors (though most in fact have pushed for and gotten fixed exchange rates). This should be imposed on them by law. In the US case, congress should impose currency board rules with a unit of account of representative goods. -- WC
Q: If central banks and politicians have demonstrated for many years now that they will ignore rules whenever it suits their interests and cave in to political pressure to spend money and then (if necessary) create new money out of thin air to keep the system from imploding as best they can, why should we believe they will change their behavior and follow a rules based Currency Board and a real world anchor for the currency?
A: Central banks do not (or rarely) ignore the law (rules) governing their behavior. Historically, it was the government seeking easy finance that push/forced their central banks to print money for them. The move of the last 40 years for independent central banks has largely solved that problem. But try as they might, even independent central banks find it difficult to achieve inflation targets most of the time. Ridged rules such as a fixed rate of growth of some monetary aggregate have not worked well and require discretion to make adjustments.
Current congressional proposals (a draft law now in congress) would require the Fed to chose its own rule, such as a Taylor rule, as the default and if it believes circumstances call for a change, it would have to explain to congress why it thought so and did so. This is about as good a realistic rule as you can get with floating exchange rates. All currency boards (I exclude Argentina from the list as they were not a full fledged currency board) have followed currency board rules faithfully and with good result. The Bretton Woods, gold exchange standard system was too flexible and allowed central banks to drift too far from its requirements ultimately forcing adjustments in exchange rates. With good (realistic) rules imposed by law, I have full confidence the Fed will follow them with good results. -- WC
Me: The only comment I can offer related to all this (the proposal to implement a Currency Board) is that I sincerely believe the #1 priority of policy makers at this point should be to try and restore the faith and confidence of the public in public officials. I think this has really been damaged as the average person gets up and goes to work every day trying to do the best they can to follow the rules and make an honest living. Then, they see that some are allowed to break or bend rules (sometimes greatly enriching themselves in the process) to such an extent that they put the entire financial system at risk and yet never seem to suffer any consequences for their behavior. I cannot tell you how many emails I have gotten over the years doing this blog from people disillusioned by what they perceive is a "rigged system" that favors some over others simply because they happen to work for a "too big to fail" entity. They feel like no one bailed out their company and people lost their jobs simply because the company where they worked was not important enough to impact the overall financial system.
Dr. Coats: Most of the complaints from the public of a "rigged system" pertain to banking and financial sector supervision rather than monetary policy. They are related but very different issues. See my article on financial supervision: "Changing direction on bank regulation" Cayman Financial Review, April 2014 -- http://www.caymanfinancialreview.com/2015/04/22/Changing-direction-on-bank-regulation/
End of Q & A Section
Note: In the link provided by Dr. Coats above, he provides his ideas on how to restore public trust and confidence in both the monetary system and the banking system. See this followup article for more.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Below is the full draft of Dr. Coats new paper which gives some historical background leading up to his proposal for a Currency Board and a hard anchor for a new global reserve currency. If readers have any comments they would like to offer just email me or post them below and I will pass them on. (email: lonestarwhitehouse@gmail.com)
Here is the concluding paragraph of the paper below to give you an idea of how Dr. Coats thinks about where central banks should be headed:
"Central banks need to return to monetary regimes with hard anchors in which money is issued in response to public demand under currency board rules. Removing any uncertainty about the value of money would facilitate market adjustments to changing environments and shocks, and would force governments to manage their fiscal policies without recourse to manipulation of monetary policy. While countercyclical monetary policy targeting inflation or NGDP might potentially reduce the amplitude of swings in employment and output, it is not obvious that it would produce faster long-term growth and, if history is any guide, it is highly unlikely that it would hit its intended target." -- WC
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Current congressional proposals (a draft law now in congress) would require the Fed to chose its own rule, such as a Taylor rule, as the default and if it believes circumstances call for a change, it would have to explain to congress why it thought so and did so. This is about as good a realistic rule as you can get with floating exchange rates. All currency boards (I exclude Argentina from the list as they were not a full fledged currency board) have followed currency board rules faithfully and with good result. The Bretton Woods, gold exchange standard system was too flexible and allowed central banks to drift too far from its requirements ultimately forcing adjustments in exchange rates. With good (realistic) rules imposed by law, I have full confidence the Fed will follow them with good results. -- WC
Me: The only comment I can offer related to all this (the proposal to implement a Currency Board) is that I sincerely believe the #1 priority of policy makers at this point should be to try and restore the faith and confidence of the public in public officials. I think this has really been damaged as the average person gets up and goes to work every day trying to do the best they can to follow the rules and make an honest living. Then, they see that some are allowed to break or bend rules (sometimes greatly enriching themselves in the process) to such an extent that they put the entire financial system at risk and yet never seem to suffer any consequences for their behavior. I cannot tell you how many emails I have gotten over the years doing this blog from people disillusioned by what they perceive is a "rigged system" that favors some over others simply because they happen to work for a "too big to fail" entity. They feel like no one bailed out their company and people lost their jobs simply because the company where they worked was not important enough to impact the overall financial system.
End of Q & A Section
Note: In the link provided by Dr. Coats above, he provides his ideas on how to restore public trust and confidence in both the monetary system and the banking system. See this followup article for more.
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Below is the full draft of Dr. Coats new paper which gives some historical background leading up to his proposal for a Currency Board and a hard anchor for a new global reserve currency. If readers have any comments they would like to offer just email me or post them below and I will pass them on. (email: lonestarwhitehouse@gmail.com)
Here is the concluding paragraph of the paper below to give you an idea of how Dr. Coats thinks about where central banks should be headed:
"Central banks need to return to monetary regimes with hard anchors in which money is issued in response to public demand under currency board rules. Removing any uncertainty about the value of money would facilitate market adjustments to changing environments and shocks, and would force governments to manage their fiscal policies without recourse to manipulation of monetary policy. While countercyclical monetary policy targeting inflation or NGDP might potentially reduce the amplitude of swings in employment and output, it is not obvious that it would produce faster long-term growth and, if history is any guide, it is highly unlikely that it would hit its intended target." -- WC
Here is the concluding paragraph of the paper below to give you an idea of how Dr. Coats thinks about where central banks should be headed:
"Central banks need to return to monetary regimes with hard anchors in which money is issued in response to public demand under currency board rules. Removing any uncertainty about the value of money would facilitate market adjustments to changing environments and shocks, and would force governments to manage their fiscal policies without recourse to manipulation of monetary policy. While countercyclical monetary policy targeting inflation or NGDP might potentially reduce the amplitude of swings in employment and output, it is not obvious that it would produce faster long-term growth and, if history is any guide, it is highly unlikely that it would hit its intended target." -- WC
-----------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
What is wrong with our monetary policy?
By Warren Coats (draft version)
“The Fed should be
using its economic expertise to highlight the long-term devastating impacts of
failing to provide the opportunity for the skills needed for the economy of the
future,” Sen. Jeff Merkley of Oregon said this summer.[1]
While it is a bit of a
challenge to tease out what Senator Merkley really wants the Fed to do, his
statement does epitomize the propensity of politicians to assign objectives to
the Fed that it doesn’t have the power to achieve while neglecting those
measures for which they themselves are responsible. So what can and should the Fed do?
Until President
Richard Nixon closed the gold window on August 15, 1971, and in 1973
permanently ended the United States’ commitment to exchange its currency held
by other central banks for gold at the fixed price of $35 per ounce, U.S.
monetary policy had been guided by and constrained by its commitments under the
gold exchange standard adopted in the Bretton Woods agreements of 1945. The gathering at Bretton Woods New Hampshire
in July 1944 led to the creation the International Monetary Fund, the World
Bank, and what is now the World Trade Organization. The irresponsible Guns AND Butter spending of
the Johnson administration on the war in Viet Nam and the war on poverty had
undermined the fiscal discipline required by the gold exchange standard. Since its abandonment, the Federal Reserve
and other central banks have searched for and experimented with a variety of alternative
approaches to monetary policy with floating exchange rates.
From the end of the Korean
War through 1965 inflation measured by the consumer price index averaged around
2% per annum but rose the second half of the 1960s to 6% by the end of the decade. [2]
Along with closing the gold window,
Nixon launched a 90 day wage and price
freeze on August 15, 1971, which turned into an almost three year period of
wage and price controls. When they were finally lifted the CPI increased a
staggering 12% in 1974. Over
this period the Fed implemented monetary policy via adjustments in the
overnight interbank lending rate (the Fed funds rate) in light of, among other
things, its objectives for the growth of monetary aggregates. However, during this period the monetary
aggregates played more the role of indicators of policy than of targets.
By the 1970s the Fed and the economics profession more
generally had accepted fact that monetary policy influences economic activity
and employment only temporarily, i.e. that in the long run there is no trade
off between employment and inflation (a vertical long run Philips Curve). Nonetheless, during this period the Fed
remained more sensitive to increases in unemployment than inflation and tended
to ease monetary policy more quickly when employment was threatened than it
tightened it in the face of increases in inflation. As the effects of changes in monetary policy
take one to two years to show up in employment and inflation (Friedman’s “long
and variable lags” in the effects of monetary policy), policy decisions need to
be based on forecasts of their future impact. Thus the Fed’s bias toward fighting
unemployment was compounded because during this period the Fed’s economic
forecasting models persistently underestimated NAIRU—the Non-Accelerating
Inflation Rate of Unemployment, also called the natural rate of
unemployment—leading the Fed to maintain “easy money” conditions for too long.
The net result of these factors was that with ever higher
inflation peaks the market’s expectations of future inflation began to
increase. Expected inflation was
increasingly built into wage agreements.
During this period higher inflation was empirically associated with
higher unemployment (a positively sloped Philips Curve). Growing public and Congressional concern with
inflation and broader professional acceptance of the “Monetarist” views of
Milton Friedman resulted in 1977 in amendments to the Federal Reserve Act to
clarify the Fed’s mandate as the pursuit of stable prices, maximum employment,
and moderate long-term interest rates.
To further tighten congressional guidance of monetary policy
and to remove its inflationary bias Congress enacted the Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act of 1978, commonly called
the Humphrey-Hawkins act, which required, among many other provisions, that the
Fed establish targets for the growth of monetary aggregates and to report them
and progress in achieving them to Congress twice yearly. Given the widely accepted fact that monetary
policy has no long run effect on employment, determining maximum employment
consistent with stable prices (NAIRU) was an important challenge for fulfilling
the Fed’s congressional mandates.
In the face of the Fed’s persistent over shooting of its
narrow and broad money target ranges and the entrenching of higher and higher
inflation expectations in wage and price increases, Federal Reserve Board
Chairman Paul Volcker led the Board and the Federal Open Market Committee
(FOMC) on October 6, 1979 in a dramatic change in the Fed’s approach to
implementing monetary policy by shifting to an intermediate, narrow money
target, operationally implemented via a target for non-borrowed reserves. The new approach required the Fed to relax its
Fed funds rate targets and it increased the band set by the FOMC for the Fed funds
rate from 0.5% to 4%. The most important
element of this dramatic shift was the acceptance by the Fed of its responsibility
for inflation and elevating its objective of price stability to first place.
Volcker
explained the Board’s thinking in his first Humphrey-Hawkins testimony on
February 19, 1980:
In
the past, at critical junctures for economic stabilization policy, we have
usually been more preoccupied with the possibility of near-term weakness in
economic activity or other objectives than with the implications of our actions
for future inflation. To some degree,
that has been true even during the long period of expansion since 1975. As a consequence, fiscal and monetary
policies alike too often have been prematurely or excessively stimulative, or
insufficiently restrictive. The result
has been our now chronic inflationary problem, with a growing conviction on the
part of many that this process is likely to continue.
. . .
The
broad objective of policy must be to break that ominous pattern. That is why dealing with inflation has
properly been elevated to a position of high national priority. Success will
require that policy be consistently and persistently oriented to that end. Vacillation and procrastination, out of fears
of recession or otherwise, would run grave risks. Amid the present uncertainties, stimulative
policies could well be misdirected in the short run; more importantly, far from
assuring more growth over time, by aggravating the inflationary process and
psychology they would threaten more instability and unemployment.
A detailed inside review by David Lindsey of Fed policy
formulation from 1975 to 2002 states that: “The Federal Reserve discovered that
pragmatic money targeting could not be done on a computer, as Milton Friedman
had advocated. Communicating the ins and
outs of monetary targeting in practice similarly was not easy….
“Experience with the extreme volatility of desired holdings
of transactions balances was fresh for the FOMC going into its July 9 [1980]
meeting. Small wonder that the
Committee's initial decision was as laid out in its Humphrey-Hawkins report to the Congress:
“While there is broad agreement in the Committee that it is
appropriate to plan for some further progress in 1981 toward reduction of the
targeted ranges, most members believe it would be premature at this time to set
forth precise ranges for each monetary aggregate for next year, given the
uncertainty of the economic outlook and institutional changes affecting the
relationships among the aggregates.”[3]
On July 1, 1982, in the midst of the relatively sharp
recession of 1981-2, the Fed raised its narrow money growth target and started
lowering the funds rate. Then, in
October, it gave up its intermediate money targeting and dropped the non-borrowed
reserves operating target. The Fed’s
abandonment of tight targets for monetary aggregates represented a failure, to
some extent at least, in Congress’ intention to provide the Fed with clear
policy rules.
In response to Volcker’s July 1982 Humphrey-Hawkins report
to an unhappy congress:
“The report continued ‘if changed conditions merit a change
in the targets, then a change in the ranges should be reported. If ranges are not changed, they should be
hit. The current policy of
'brinksmanship' in which the Federal Reserve announces that it is aiming for
the ceiling of its ranges, is unsatisfactory.
The Federal Open Market Committee should, at its next meeting, correct
its presentation of its targets and report either a change or no change in its
announced aggregate-growth target ranges.’"[4]
Despite these difficulties—the fed funds rate rose
temporarily to over 22% and GDP fell by over 2% in
1982—actual and expected inflation were reversed and fell below 2½% by
1983.
Importantly, having licked inflation, the Fed continued to
give primacy to its price stability mandate, though with a more flexible and
traditional operational approach. The
era of the great moderation in the volatility of GDP and inflation followed but
the search for suitable monetary policy operational rules continued.
The non-borrowed reserves operating target of October 1979 to October 1982 was replaced with a
borrowed reserve target. It was not
without difficulties. The straw that
broke the camel’s back was reported by Lindsey:
“Eating Humble Pie
along with the Thanksgiving Turkey
November 22, 1989
Just before Thanksgiving 1989, the Manager was, as in
previous months, trying to implement the procedures geared mainly to an
operating target for adjustment plus seasonal borrowings. He had been attempting to place primary
emphasis on reserve needs in Desk operations and secondary importance on the
funds rate quoted in the market at the time of Desk action. On that Wednesday before Thanksgiving, the
Desk needed to add reserves for technical reasons. Even though the funds rate slipped from 1/16
percentage point to 1/8 percentage point below the Committee's funds rate
expectation just before the operation, the Desk still arranged a five-day
System repurchase agreement (RP). Market participants interpreted the operation
as signaling a policy move, when it in fact did not. On Friday morning, the New York Times cited
‘government officials’ claiming (albeit erroneously) that an easing had taken
place. The policy record of the December
meeting that year mentioned the episode: ‘Conditions in reserve markets
softened temporarily around Thanksgiving when operations to meet seasonal
reserve needs were misread as signaling a further easing of monetary
policy.’ After the incident, the Desk
put top priority on signaling the Committee's intended funds rate. And that's the story of how the FOMC lost its
borrowing procedures.”[5]
At about the same time radical innovations in the
development of monetary policy rules were launched by the Reserve Bank of New
Zealand, which came to be known as explicit inflation targeting.[6] An inflation target provides a clear and
explicit rule that permits flexible operational approaches to its
achievement. Given Friedman’s long and
variable lags in the effect of monetary policy, setting monetary operational
targets (almost always the equivalent of a fed funds rate) must be based on the
best model assisted forecast of its consistency with the inflation target one
to two years in the future. A longer
target horizon provided more scope for smoothing the output gap (employment). Full transparency of the policy and the data
and reasoning underlying policy settings is required to gain the benefits of
the alignment of market inflation expectations with the policy target.[7]
The RBNZ’s development and adoption of inflation targeting
was an important development in the pursuit of rule based monetary policy with
floating exchange rates that accommodated flexible implementation. It swept the world of central banking.[8] While the Fed did not adopt explicit
inflation targets until 2012, it clearly pursued an implicit inflation target
long before that.
The FOMC made its inflation target explicit in January 2012:
“The inflation rate over the longer run is primarily
determined by monetary policy, and hence the Committee has the ability to
specify a longer-run goal for inflation. The Committee judges that inflation at
the rate of 2 percent, as measured by the annual change in the price index for
personal consumption expenditures, is most consistent over the longer run with
the Federal Reserve’s statutory mandate….
“The maximum level of employment is largely determined by
nonmonetary factors that affect the structure and dynamics of the labor
market. These factors may change over
time and may not be directly measurable.
Consequently, it would not be appropriate to specify a fixed goal for
employment; rather, the Committee's policy decisions must be informed by
assessments of the maximum level of employment, recognizing that such
assessments are necessarily uncertain and subject to revision.”[9]
The Great Recession of December 2007 to June 2009 highlighted the failure of inflation targeting to
take account of asset price bubbles
and for "inappropriate responses to supply shocks and terms-of trade
shocks".[10] What followed can only be described as a
nightmare (largely because of weaknesses in the U.S. financial system). After properly and successfully performing
its function of a lender of last resort and thus preventing a liquidity-induced
collapse of the banking system, the Fed went on to undertake ever more desperate
measures to reflate the economy. These Quantitative
Easing (QE), quasi-fiscal activities have been widely discussed and have
contributed little to economic recovery.[11]
With
the “failure” of inflation targeting, nominal GDP targeting is now gaining
support. With a NGDP target when real
GDP slows or falls, the inflation target is automatically increased in
countercyclical fashion. The rationale
for this approach reflects the view inspired by Keynesian
aggregate demand management that government
policy, whether fiscal or monetary, can assist the market’s own adjustments to
shocks of one sort or another. While
measures of aggregate demand can be useful for analysis, actual government
expenditure components of aggregate demand are specific to individual projects
and unlikely to coincide with areas of actual excess capacity. NGDP targeting also ignores the role and
benefits of stable money (a constant, preferably zero, rate of inflation) for
private market calculations and adjustments to changing real circumstances. Investor must augment their assessments of
real economic conditions and prospects with their guesses about monetary policy
and its impact.
Each
household’s, or region’s, or country’s balance of payments with the rest of the
world is regulated by individual budget constraints—what the household is able
to produce (its income) and is thus capable of buying (smoothed by what it is
able to borrow and/or has previously saved).
Dynamic, growing economies are always adjusting to changing consumer
tastes, new technologies, failed firms, changes in prices of internationally
traded goods, etc. These adjustments,
which may entail painful periods of retraining and/or unemployment for workers,
and capital reallocation for firms are a necessary aspect of growing economies.
The goal of all active stabilization
policies, fiscal or monetary, is to reduce the pain of market adjustments to
shocks by actively adding to deficient demand or diminishing excess demand,
thus spreading the adjustment over a longer period. The passive elements of fiscal
policy—automatic stabilizers such as unemployment insurance—are generally
accepted as helpful along with the rest of the social safety net.
The potential,
temporary contribution of monetary policy to smoothing swings in output come
from speeding up adjustment by pushing interest rates even lower than would
market forces alone during downswings and higher than the market alone
would produce when output is over heating.
This can be achieved by pushing money growth above the growth in its
demand or visa versa (or equivalently by pushing interest rates below or raising
them above their natural real rate). Interest
rates below the full employment rate (by more than the market would produce on
its own) should encourage increased borrowing and investment, increases in
asset prices (including real estate) that increase consumption, and
depreciation of exchange rates that increase net exports and thus a quicker
closing of the output gap.
When
interest rates are lowered to zero (the lower zero bound), consumption and
investment cannot be stimulated further via the interest rate channel for
transmitting monetary policy nor can they further depreciate the exchange
rate. Consumption can potentially be
stimulated via the wealth effect of increasing asset prices but at the expense
of distorting resource allocation (asset bubbles). This leaves negative real interest rates
(e.g. by increasing inflation) and helicopter money (increased government transfers,
e.g. by the reduction of social security wage taxes, financed by printing
money).
For
these countercyclical policies to make a positive contribution to price and
output stability, the central bank must be able to correctly forecast the
interest rate or money supply required for the inflation or NGDP targets in one
to two years in the future. This
requires, among other things, correctly determining the natural real rate of
interest and sustainable real output, both of which are unobservable. The conclusion from the above history is that
monetary policy is being asked to deliver more than it is capable of
delivering. Central banks are generally
staffed by very capable people, but they can never know all that they need to
know to keep the economy at full employment as employers and jobs keep changing.
The quality of forecasting models has greatly improved in recent years but they
remain unreliable. In addition, politicians
like Senator Jeff Merkley expect the Fed to perform miracles that are
beyond its capacity while Congress continues to spend and regulate
destructively. In my opinion, central
banks have given their price stability mandates their best shot and
failed. The successful management of the
money supply with floating exchange rates is simply beyond the capacity of
mortals.
The alternative is to return to a hard anchor for monetary
policy. This means linking the value of
money to something real and managing its supply consistent with that value
(exchange rate). Such regimes do not
magically overcome a economy’s many and continuous resource allocation and
coordination challenges, but by providing a stable unit in which to value goods
and services and to evaluate investment options, and sufficient liquidity with
which to transact, such regimes facilitate the continuous adjustments private
actors need to make for an economy to remain fully employed and to grow.
The second source of failure came from fixing the value of
money to an inappropriate anchor. When
the exchange rate of a currency is fixed to another currency or commodity whose
value changes in ways that are inappropriate for the economy, domestic price
adjustments can become difficult and disruptive. Fixing the exchange rate to a single
commodity, as with the gold standard, transmitted changes in the relative price
of gold to prices in general, which imposed considerable hardships on the
public.
Consider,
for example, the previous era of globalization in the late nineteenth
century. World “wide demand for gold
rose much more than the supply from the 1870s through the mid-1890s as nearly
two dozen countries adopted or re-adopted the gold standard, and hence needed
to accumulate reserves. Two of the
world’s largest economies, the United States and France, also made growing use
of gold coins. Indeed, demand drove the
commodity-exchange value of gold to the highest level it was to reach in four
centuries of record-keeping—the flip-side of deflation of other commodity
prices. The commodity price decline
reduced profits and chilled investment demand.”[12]
These
historical weaknesses of monetary regimes with hard anchors can be overcome by
choosing better anchors and by replacing central bank management of the money
supply with market management via currency board rules. I have discussed these improvements extensively
in earlier papers but summarize them briefly here.
The
value of the IMF’s SDR is determined by the market value of fixed amounts of
(soon to be) five currencies. Such an
anchor is by its nature more stable than is the value of any one of the
currencies in the SDR’s valuation basket (USD, Euro, Yen, GBP, and RMB). Broadening a commodity anchor to include a
number of diverse commodities would be an improvement over the use of a single
commodity such as gold. The most stable
anchor relative to purchasing power would be the basket of goods in a
representative consumer price index basket (CPI). Such an anchor is proposed in my Real SDR Currency Board paper.[13][14]
The
public will demand to hold an amount of money (currency plus transaction
deposits at banks) in light of the value of its anchor that generally varies
with income and the opportunity cost of holding money (interest rates). In addition, however, advances in payment
technology and innovations in financial instruments have affected and will
continue to affect the demand for money.
These variations in money demand create serious challenges to central
bank management of the supply of money that do not exist when issuing currency
via currency board rules in response to market demand. Under currency board rules the public can
always buy and hold exactly the amount of money it wants at its official anchor
price.
Central
banks need to return to monetary regimes with hard anchors in which money is issued
in response to public demand under currency board rules. Removing any uncertainty about the value of
money would facilitate market adjustments to changing environments and shocks,
and would force governments to manage their fiscal policies without recourse to
manipulation of monetary policy. While
countercyclical monetary policy targeting inflation or NGDP might potentially
reduce the amplitude of swings in employment and output, it is not obvious that
it would produce faster long-term growth and, if history is any guide, it is
highly unlikely that it would hit its intended target.
--------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
Warren
Coats retired from the International Monetary Fund in 2003 where he led
technical assistance missions to the central banks of more than twenty
countries (including Afghanistan, Bosnia, Egypt, Iraq, Kenya, Serbia, Turkey,
and Zimbabwe). He was Chief of the SDR
Division of the Finance Department of the IMF from 1982-88 and a visiting
economist at the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve in 1979. He has a BA in economics from U.C Berkeley
and a PhD in economics from the University of Chicago.
[1]
Ylan Q. Mui, https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/wonk/wp/2016/08/26/liberals-fought-for-janet-yellen-to-lead-the-fed-now-they-hope-shes-more-more-ally-than-adversary/ The
Washington Post Aug. 27, 2016
[2] In addition to closing the Gold window and a 90-day wage and price freeze, the Nixon Shock also included a 10% surcharge on existing tariffs on imports.
[3] David E. Lindsey, A Modern History of FOMC Communication: 1975-2002 FOMC Secretariat, June 24, 2003 page 55.
[4] Lindsey, Ibid. page 60.
[5] Lindsey, Ibid. page 93.
[6] Key roles in developing the forecasting models and decision making processes at the RBNZ and subsequently at the Bank of Canada and else where were played by Doug Laxton and David Rose at that time from the Bank of Canada.
[7] Geoffrey Heenan, Marcel Peter, and Scott Roger, 2006, “Implementing Inflation Targeting: Institutional Arrangements, Target Design, and Communication,” IMF Working Paper 06/278 (Washington: International Monetary Fund)
[8] As of March 2012, 28 central banks had formally adopted inflation targeting policy regimes.
[9] Minutes of the Federal Open Market Committee, January 24–25, 2012.
[11] See for example, Warren Coats, “US Monetary Policy: QE3”, Cayman Financial Review January 2013.
[12] Clark Johnson, “Did Keynes Make His Case?” Journal of Economics Library Vol 3, Issue 2, June 2016.
[14] The very important feature of indirect redeemability (issuing and redeeming SDRs for assets of equivalent value rather than the goods in the basket) is discussed in the above article as well.
References
Coats, Warren "The D E Fs of the
Financial Markets Crisis" CATO Institute, September 26, 2008.
_______ "The Big
Bailout--What Next?", CATO Institute, October 3, 2008.
_______ (Editor) Inflation
Targeting in Transition Economies: The Case of the Czech Republic, (Prague:
Czech National Bank and Washington DC: International Monetary Fund) 2000.
_______ with
Douglas Laxton, and David Rose (Editors),
The Czech National Bank's forecasting and policy analysis system, Czech
National Bank (Prague), March 2003).
______ "Real
SDR Currency Board", Central
Banking Journal XXII.2 (2011), also available at http://works.bepress.com/warren_coats/25
______ “US
Monetary Policy: QE3”, Cayman Financial Review January 2013. http://www.caymanfinancialreview.com/2013/01/11/US-monetary-policy--QE3/
______ "A
modest proposal: Helicopter money and pension reform," Cayman Financial Review, May 2016
Heenan, Geoffrey,
Marcel Peter, and Scott Roger, 2006, “Implementing Inflation Targeting:
Institutional Arrangements, Target Design, and Communication,” IMF Working
Paper 06/278 (Washington: International Monetary Fund)
Johnson, Clark.
“Did Keynes Make His Case?” Journal of Economics Library Vol 3, Issue 2, June
2016.
David E. Lindsey,
A Modern History of FOMC Communication:
1975-2002 FOMC Secretariat, June 24, 2003.
______ A
Century of Monetary Policy at the Fed, Palgrave Macmillan, 2016.
_______ with Athanasios Orphanides, and Robert H.
Rasche, “The Reform of October 1979: How It Happened and Why” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review
March/April, 2005.
Nature is a wonderful thing, and as the commercial told us, `Its not nice to fool Mother Nature!'
ReplyDeleteAs long as men determine our monetary policies there will be problems. Nature is a wonderful thing and reaches beyond trees, animals and even humans, Economics are part of Nature and that is why Nature gave us Gold and Silver!
As long as men continue to try to fool Mother Nature with Keynesian Economics we will have hell to pay! Keynesianism is a Religion NOT Economics. Keynesianism is a nightmare dreamed by a fool!
We need to follow Natural Law, Natural Economic Law or Says Law which states that economic stability is derived from macroeconomic activity. In other words, the entire economic system has to be able to function FREE of government intervention in order to create a Free Market Economy free of shortages or over production.
I repeat: As long as men determine our monetary policies there will be problems. However, Nature gave us Gold and Silver, and as long as we allow the price of Gold and Silver to float freely we have the perfect Economic System. There will always be enough Gold and Silver to accommodate the economy because the of the law of Supply and Demand, or as I like to say, Price and Demand; as demand increases so will the price.
Take oil for example, right now there is little demand for oil, so the price drops. As the economy picks up, so will the demand for oil and therefore, so will the price!
Gold is presently at about $1300 per ounce, but as the demand for Gold increases so will the price. If we reintroduce Gold into the monetary system the price of Gold will naturally increase. Or more correctly, if we scrap our bogus, artificial and Un-Constitutional monetary system and return to a Constitutional monetary system based on Gold and Silver, the metals will naturally find Economic Price Equilibrium!
There is a video online that explains it clearly:
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=hCXjS04xEZk
About 3/4 way into the video a gentleman explains that 1500 years ago One Dinar (Gold coin) bought two head of goat and today One Dinar STILL buys two head of goat!
This comment has been removed by the author.
ReplyDeleteThank you for the comments!
ReplyDeleteYou're welcome.
DeleteAre you Lawrence H. White (born November 27, 1954)?
Just curious.
Thanks,
No, I actually mention that I am not that Lawrence White in the FAQ section of the blog. I am writing from the perspective of a non expert with interest in these issues.
Delete